Both the UK and the EU have made commitments to
achieve carbon neutrality by 2050. Political leaders
all over the world have promised ‘new green deals’
that involve embracing large-scale government
intervention. These policies lead to substantial
resources being allocated on the basis of politicians’
own technological preferences, rather than according
to the principles of economic and technical efficiency.
• Energy sources are both taxed and subsidised. In
principle, environmental taxes and subsidies should
reflect externalities. However, in practice, policy is
chaotic with tax treatment reflecting the nature of
the fuel, who consumes the fuel and for what purpose
the fuel is used. In some countries, renewable energy
receives large subsidies with little or no regard to
the environmental benefit they actually deliver.
Furthermore, fossil fuels are generally subsidised too.
In the UK, that happens by an exemption from the
general rate of value added tax.
• On average, oil products are taxed at €405 per tonne
of oil equivalent in the UK and €334 in the EU27, as
compared with €135 and €101 for natural gas and €112
and €84 for coal. This is despite the fact that coal, not
oil, poses the largest environmental challenges as far
as climate change is concerned.
• Energy sources, including those that are taxed and
including fossil fuels, are also heavily subsidised. In
2018 energy subsidies were as high as €500 per head
in the UK and €355 in the EU27. Most subsidies were
given to renewable energy sources, the production
of which was subsidised by €448 per tonne of oil
equivalent on average in the UK and €320 in the EU27.
Subsidies were higher for solar photovoltaics (€1,468
per tonne of oil equivalent in the UK and €2,019 in
the EU27), followed by wind power (€961 and €743,
respectively). Hydro power and bio-energies received,
on average, much lower subsidies. These differential
subsidies to different forms of renewable energy
sources are wasteful and inefficient. Subsidies to fossil
fuels were generally intended to support consumption
rather than production. On average, oil, natural gas
and coal received €130, €61 and €86 per tonne of oil
equivalent in subsidies in the UK and €320, €47 and
€27 respectively in the EU27.
• If we net off taxes and subsidies, we find that, on
balance, renewables are heavily subsidised, while
fossil fuels have greater taxes levied on them than they
receive in subsidies. However, there is no coherent
pattern. The net effect of taxes and subsidies leads to
substantially greater net taxes on oil than on natural
gas while coal is taxed the least. The level of net taxes
on energy sources does not, in any way, relate to the
externalities from the energy source.
• If the EU-sponsored estimates of external costs from
energy sources is taken as a benchmark, it can be
said that all energy sources are either under-taxed or
over-subsidised.
• It is clear that taxes and subsidies on energy sources
are not designed as a rational tool of environmental
policy. They are part of a broader industrial policy that
reflects the individual preferences of policymakers
and the producer and consumer interest groups that
influence them.
• This means that current green policies are more
costly than they need be. A rational system that taxed
energy sources according to the damage caused by
their emissions would ensure that greater levels of
carbon reduction would be possible for a much lower
economic cost. It would also make use of decentralised
information, as individuals would be able to reduce
carbon emissions in the way that was least costly for
them.
• Climate change is by no means the only externality
from the use of energy. Many other externalities
have a local, not a global, nature. The problems are
not significantly different from a range of other
scenarios where economic activity by one party has
an impact on another party. Externalities with a local
impact do not justify either taxes or subsidies at the
national level. They require a legal, institutional and
constitutional framework which allows the maximum
scope for preferences to be expressed through various
bargaining and charging mechanisms at the local level.
• Decarbonisation has been established as a key policy
objective for the UK and the EU. Economic efficiency,
including efficiency of capital allocation, are especially
important in this process given the immense costs
involved. For this reason, the government should stop
its policies of trying to pick winners, subsidising fossil
fuels and subsidising renewables and levy a carbon tax
proportional to emissions. Estimates of the damage
caused by emissions may vary and those used by the
EU are contestable. Thus, there is room for debate
on how big a carbon tax should be. However, this is
the most efficient mechanism available for reducing
carbon emissions.
• The proceeds of a carbon tax should be used directly to
reduce the tax burden in other areas. Welfare benefits
would be uprated as a result of the impact of a carbon
tax on prices. The aim of a carbon tax is to price
carbon and not to increase the tax burden.
• The invasion of Ukraine by Russia does not change the
argument. Indeed, it makes it more important that we
adopt policies that lead to the efficient consumption
and production of energy